WeeklyWorker

19.07.2018

The Keynesian dilemma

Will it be free trade or protectionism? Michael Roberts examines the contending views

The trade war that has broken out has confused mainstream macroeconomics. The majority still see tariff increases as ‘protectionism’ and regard ‘free trade’ as the only way to operate - Donald Trump’s measures are generally condemned. But among the Keynesians there is confusion and disagreement.

Martin Wolf, the Keynesian economic journalist who writes for the Financial Times, had reckoned that any trade war would be costly for global capital: “Global cooperation would surely be shattered.”1 Nevertheless, he argued for UK retaliation against Trump’s measures - “more because the alternative looks weak than in the belief that it would work. Another thing the rest of the world should do is to strengthen their cooperation.” On the other hand, he thought Trump’s wild proposal to create a tariff-free area (for rich countries only) could be taken up: “Who knows? It might even work.” He did not explain how cutting tariffs on goods from the 3%-4% that they average now for most advanced countries to zero would make any difference.

While Wolf looks for ways to ‘save globalisation and free trade’ through retaliation, another Keynesian, Dani Rodrik, actually advocates protectionism as a good idea for economies with weak domestic growth: “US protectionism surely will generate some beneficiaries as well in other countries.”2

In a contrary view to Wolf, who calls for retaliation to stand up to Trump, Rodrik contends that Europe and China should “should refuse to be drawn into a trade war, and say to Trump: you are free to damage your own economy; we will stick by policies that work best for us”. Indeed, he says, domestic industries may benefit from tariffs on their exports to the US - they could sell at home instead. He cites how Boeing could sell more planes in the US and Airbus could do the same in Europe:

Some European airlines favour Boeing over Airbus, while some US airlines prefer Airbus over Boeing. Trade restrictions may result in a total collapse in this large volume of two-way trade in aircraft between the US and Europe. But the overall loss in economic welfare would be small, so long as airlines view the two companies’ products as close substitutes.

The protectionist line has also been peddled by leftist economist Dean Baker.3 He points out that not everyone gains from ‘free trade’. He claims that it was free trade that lost manufacturing jobs in the US, echoing the Trumpist argument. However, there is much evidence that this was not the case. As I said previously regarding Trump, trade and technology,

the loss of US manufacturing jobs, as it has been in other advanced capitalist economies, is not due to nasty foreigners fixing trade deals. It is due to the inexorable attempt of American capital to reduce its labour costs through mechanisation or through finding new cheap labour areas overseas to produce. The rising inequality in incomes is a product of ‘capital bias’ in capitalist accumulation and ‘globalisation’ aimed at counteracting falling profitability in the advanced capitalist economies. But it is also the result of ‘neoliberal’ policies designed to hold down wages and boost profit share.4

Baker claims that trade deficits lose jobs because they reduce “demand” and so reducing the US trade deficit would save jobs. He makes this argument when the official unemployment rate in the US, the UK and Japan is at an all-time low (yes, I know many are crap jobs)! Apparently, if everybody ran a trade surplus (impossible, by the way), all would be better off. What he really means is Trump is right to turn the US trade deficit into a surplus and get manufacturing jobs back from the developing world and Europe. It is certainly a weird and confused argument for nationalism.

Keynes

The Keynesians are confused about whether they favour ‘free trade’ or protectionist/nationalist measures. This echoes the confusion that Keynes had during the last great depression of the 1930s. He changed from being a strong free trader in the late 1920s to a protectionist and advocate of tariffs by the mid-1930s. This was really an expression of a changing view of British capitalism. Free trade is fine for those winning in markets; protectionism is better when a national capital loses share. And that was Britain’s position.

In 1923, Keynes endorsed free trade in no uncertain terms:

We must hold to free trade, in its widest interpretation, as an inflexible dogma, to which no exception is admitted, wherever the decision rests with us. We must hold to this even where we receive no reciprocity of treatment and even in those rare cases where by infringing it we could in fact obtain a direct economic advantage. We should hold to free trade as a principle of international morals, and not merely as a doctrine of economic advantage.5

But his ‘moral’ position soon dissipated, as British capitalism fell into a long depression in the mid-1920s and then in the 1930s. In his 1936 seminal work, The general theory, he concluded:

... the one big (and smart) idea of absolute monarchy was to push exports over imports … A favourable balance, provided it is not too large, will prove extremely stimulating; whilst an unfavourable balance may soon produce a state of persistent depression.6

He advocated tariffs on imports into the UK as an alternative way of cutting real wages (by increased import prices) and to boost domestic production. For Keynes, it was a way for British capital to gain an advantage over its rivals by reducing wage costs in real terms. “I am frightfully afraid of protection as a long-term policy,” he testified to a UK parliamentary commission, “but we cannot afford always to take long views ... the question, in my opinion, is how far I am prepared to risk long-period disadvantages in order to get some help to the immediate position”.7 Of course, once capitalism globally had recovered, and with it British capital, then ‘free trade’ could be renewed.

The current confusion in macroeconomics and particularly among modern Keynesians mirrors the changing views of Keynes, as the current long depression lingers and ‘globalisation’ fails for all. So now we have Keynesians like Rodrik and Baker supporting tariffs on US imports and pushing for trade surpluses, while calling on Europe and China not to retaliate! And Wolf calls for retaliation by Europe and Asia.

Marxism

What is the Marxist view? Should we support tariffs and other protectionist measures introduced by weaker capitalist nations to ‘stand up’ to Trump’s measures (Wolf)? Alternatively should we support Trump’s measures as a way of saving US manufacturing jobs (Baker) and perhaps helping other countries to boost their domestic industries (Rodrik)?

Free trade or protection? I outlined my answer in a previous article.8 Free trade has been no great capitalist success. Capitalism does not tend to equilibrium in the process of accumulation. As Adam Smith put it, in contrast to Ricardo,

When a rich man and a poor man deal with one another, both of them will increase their riches, if they deal prudently, but the rich man’s stock will increase in a greater proportion than the poor man’s. In like manner, when a rich and a poor nation engage in trade, the rich nation will have the greatest advantage, and therefore the prohibition of this commerce is most hurtful to it of the two.9

Capitalism does not grow globally in a smooth and balanced way, but in what Marxists have called ‘uneven and combined development’. Those firms and countries with better technological advances will gain at the expense of those who are behind the curve and there will be no equalisation.

Free trade works for national capitalist states when the profitability of capital is rising (as it was from the 1980s to 2000) and everybody can gain from a larger cake (if in differing proportions). Then globalisation appears very attractive. The strongest capitalist economy (technologically and thus competitively in price-per-unit terms) will be the strongest advocate of ‘free trade’, as Britain was from 1850 to 1870, and the US was from 1945-2000. Then globalisation was the mantra of the US and its international agencies, the World Bank, the Organisation of Economic Cooperation and Development and the International Monetary Fund. But if profitability starts to fall consistently, then ‘free trade’ loses its glamour, especially for the weaker capitalist economies, as the profit cake stops getting larger.

Marx and Engels recognised that ‘free trade’ could drive capital accumulation globally and so expand economies, as has happened in the last 170 years. But they also saw the dual nature of capitalist accumulation and its other side: rising inequality, a permanently floating ‘reserve army’ of unemployed and increased exploitation of labour in the weaker economies. And so they recognised that rising industrial capitalist nations could probably only succeed through protecting their industries with tariffs and controls and even state support (China is an extreme example of that).

Engels reconsidered the case for free trade in 1888 when writing a new preface on a 1847 pamphlet by Marx on free trade. Engels concluded:

the question of free trade or protection moves entirely within the bounds of the present system of capitalist production, and has, therefore, no direct interest for us socialists who want to do away with that system. Whether you try the protectionist or the free trade will make no difference in the end.10

But it is informative to see the Keynesians split over favouring free trade for global capital (Krugman)11 or protection for national capitals (Rodrik and Baker for the US, and Wolf for the UK and Europe). Sign of the times.

Michael Roberts blogs at https://thenextrecession.wordpress.com.

Notes

1. www.ft.com/content/b327f02a-84af-11e8-a29d-73e3d454535d.

2. www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/china-europe-reaction-trump-trade-tariffs-by-dani-rodrik-2018-07.

3. https://rwer.wordpress.com/2018/07/11/six-lies-on-trade.

4. https://thenextrecession.wordpress.com/2016/12/10/trump-trade-and-technology.

5. JM Keynes Reconstruction in Europe London 1923, p717.

6. JM Keynes The general theory of employment, interest and money London 1936.

7. Ibid.

8. https://thenextrecession.wordpress.com/2018/03/19/trumps-trade-tantrums-free-trade-or-protectionism.

9. Early draft of part of the Wealth of nations, quoted in RL Meek, DD Raphael and P Stein (eds) Works and correspondence of Adam Smith Vol 5, Oxford 1978.

10. www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1888/free-trade/index.htm.

11. See https://thenextrecession.wordpress.com/2018/07/06/trade-war-and-depression.